Do Something

Tell Darrell Clarke how you feel about his parking proposal

City Council President Darrell Clarke wants to double the minimum parking requirements for new multifamily housing in his district. That could make a bigger problem than the one we already have: A dearth of available spots for residents.

Let Clarke and the other Councilmembers know what you think of the proposal.

Connect WITH OUR SOCIAL ACTION TEAM



How To Achieve Parking Peace

Want a simple solution to neighborhood parking angst? Let’s try a “Cap-and-Trade” parking permit system

How To Achieve Parking Peace

Want a simple solution to neighborhood parking angst? Let’s try a “Cap-and-Trade” parking permit system

Council President Darrell Clarke is a guy who brags about driving to the corner store, so it’s no surprise that his vision for the 5th Council District looks a lot more like the suburban sprawl of Phoenix or Atlanta than the rowhouse neighborhoods of Philadelphia.

That would be the predictable result from his new bill doubling minimum parking requirements for new multifamily housing.

This is a bad idea, as this 5-minute video from Vox illustrates:

Clarke’s proposed medicine is worse than the disease, but all this parking angst does stem from a real problem that local government is failing to address: the utter failure to manage curb parking in a sensible way.

At just $35 a permit per year, the Philadelphia Parking Authority’s permit parking program doesn’t even raise enough money to pay for itself, let alone discourage people from using the street for long-term car storage.

And most city blocks don’t currently use permit parking at all, as the city and PPA put the onus on residents to petition for permit parking on a block-by-block basis rather than opting in whole districts or neighborhoods.

As Gilles Duranton tells Jake Blumgart at PlanPhilly, increasing parking minimums has a certain logic behind it if we’re just ruling out dealing with the curb parking mismanagement, but managing curb parking is a much better approach.

Gilles Duranton, chair of the real estate department at the University of Pennsylvania’s Wharton School, agrees that free or incredibly cheap on-street parking is the crux of the problem. As long as the existing parking prices (or lack thereof) remain in place, parked cars can occupy highly valuable public land without paying for it. As neighborhoods fill again with Philadelphians who’d also like to use use that land for cheap or free, parking conflicts sharpen.

“The root of the problem is that the city is massively subsidizing on-street parking,” said Duranton.

Just how large of a subsidy are we talking about? Market prices for off-street parking range from about $150-250 a month, which adds up to about $1,800-$3,000 a year. Council charges $35 a year, which rounds to about 9 cents a day per vehicle to park long-term on the public street.

This gets at why increasing parking minimums won’t work to reduce tight curb parking. The availability of more off-street parking per se doesn’t do anything to prevent newer residents from using the free on-street parking. As long as there’s no cost to park on the street, it’s always going to be everyone’s first choice no matter how much off-street parking is built.

The only workable political solution is to give long-time residents exactly what they say they want: free parking for themselves, and more expensive parking for new residents.

In both my current neighborhood in Fishtown, and my old neighborhood in Bella Vista, a surprising number of garage owners use their garages to store personal items and park on the street anyway. New buildings will often charge separately to use the on-site parking at a rate that’s higher than the free or cheap curb parking, nudging car owners toward the free curb parking. People who own indoor spaces might also choose to rent out those spaces to someone else and park their own car on the curb. To free up more curb parking, there’s no alternative to managing the curb parking.

But it’s also almost impossible to imagine a situation where Council would vote to bump parking permit prices from $35 up to $1,800 to $3,000 a year to make them competitive with private off-street options. In addition to the bad politics of a huge fee increase, it also runs afoul of the popular desire to treat long-time residents and new residents differently (despite the fact that the streets are publicly-owned land that belongs to everyone equally).

The only workable political solution is to give long-time residents exactly what they say they want: free parking for themselves, and more expensive parking for new residents.

How To Achieve Parking Peace
Via Parkadelphia

The way to accomplish this is a Cap-and-Trade system for parking permits.

Current homeowners feel that they have a weak ‘property right’ to the parking on their block. When new houses bring more cars to the neighborhood, the value of that property right gets eroded. The current parking permit system is a step toward codifying that property right, but the problem is that it’s too weak. The PPA will just keep printing and printing them forever. In parts of Center City, the PPA has printed vastly more permits than there are curb parking spaces, greatly reducing the use value of the permits.

So the first step is to stop printing permits when you run out of curb spaces. The Parking Authority should take an inventory of the legal parking spaces in each permit district, and turn off the printer when they reach the limit. The second step is to make the permits tradeable, so the owners can sell them on Craigslist or eBay or Internet Yardsale groups on Facebook.

If you like your permit, you can keep it for as long as you want. Some people might decide though that they’d rather have the cash and sell their car, or even offload an under-used second or third car. Trade by trade, the value of the permits would eventually climb to their true market value, and we’d start to see some more curb parking spaces open on each block.

The permits would need to be tied to an address so that they would continue to be useful, rather than purely a store of value, like a taxi medallion. And in areas where permits already exceed the number of parking spaces, the permits could be reduced through attrition. Ideally the City would tax transfers at the point of sale, rather than continuing to collect the annual $35 fee. The revenue could be spent in the districts where the money was raised, or be used to reduce other taxes and fees.

What’s in it for newer residents? While this is unquestionably a better deal for incumbent homeowners, there are major benefits for newer residents to solving the curb parking problem once and for all. For one thing, it puts the cost entirely on parking users, and doesn’t force people who don’t own cars to pay for their neighbors’ parking the way Clarke’s bill does. If the cost of curb parking has to go up, people who don’t drive shouldn’t get roped into paying for that. Permit Cap-and-Trade preserves the option not to pay, and speeds up the unbundling of parking costs from housing costs.

And on a citywide level, finally dealing with the curb parking problem would have enormous economic value. So much useful economic activity is continually being blocked over concerns about free curb parking, from dense infill housing, to neighborhood retail businesses, to bike share stations, to traffic calming street changes, and on and on.

Permit Cap-and-Trade would change the politics of parking by creating a new political constituency with a vested interest in growing permit values. Permit holders who might previously have opposed new apartments down the street, or a new restaurant around the corner, on parking grounds might find their views have changed.

This idea may be a little repugnant (why should incumbent homeowners get a huge, somewhat arbitrary windfall?) but it’s the least-bad option out there. It won’t reduce the overall volume of home building like Clarke’s bill would, and it won’t drive up the cost of housing. But it would solve the problem of parking congestion in a way that’s less economically damaging than Clarke’s parking minimums bill, and doesn’t try to work against what long-time residents already believe about parking.

Jon Geeting is the director of engagement at Philadelphia 3.0, a political action committee that supports efforts to reform and modernize City Hall. This is the first of a series of articles that will run in both The Citizen and 3.0’s blog.

Header Photo: Philadelphia Parking Authority

Advertising Terms

We do not accept political ads, issue advocacy ads, ads containing expletives, ads featuring photos of children without documented right of use, ads paid for by PACs, and other content deemed to be partisan or misaligned with our mission. The Philadelphia Citizen is a 501(c)(3) nonprofit, nonpartisan organization and all affiliate content will be nonpartisan in nature. Advertisements are approved fully at The Citizen's discretion. Advertisements and sponsorships have different tax-deductible eligibility. For questions or clarification on these conditions, please contact Director of Sales & Philanthropy Kristin Long at [email protected] or call (609)-602-0145.